Both the FTC in the US and the European Commission in the EU recently launched several antitrust lawsuits against large tech companies such as Google or Facebook because they are monopolizing certain markets by driving competitors out of business and thus harming competition. Can you shed light on the main challenges and major differences between the American and the European approach?
When assessing the two regimes, keep in mind that the world’s most successful innovative companies are U.S. firms. That is in large part because the U.S. antitrust regime focuses on the behavior of a firm and not on a firm’s size, which can be the result of the competitive process. In other words,
the U.S. antitrust laws do not punish companies for successfully competing to have the best product;
a monopolist of mousetraps is permitted to charge the monopoly price because it competed with its rivals to earn that monopoly position. In the U.S., antitrust liability only attaches when the monopolist abuses its position or acquired it by nefarious means. With this conduct-focused approach,
the U.S. antitrust laws incentivize firms to innovate against the backdrop of antitrust liability,
which attaches only if their monopoly position is driven or maintained, not by competition on the merits, but by anticompetitive conduct.
Contrast the U.S. approach with the European approach. In Europe, and other countries following the European approach, firm size alone is either sufficient to establish liability or to impose strict rules on firm behavior regardless of whether a company’s monopoly position was earned by innovating and competing to produce the best product. Under that approach, success in the marketplace is often and more easily punished without requiring proof of harm to competition. That’s not the case in the U.S. The European approach gives regulators more control over the inner workings of European companies. That control dulls the incentive of those companies to innovate and compete to produce the best product. The issue is that antitrust laws are not supposed to micromanage the competitive process. They are intended to police abuses that create monopoly power.
Like the U.S., the proffered goal of the antitrust laws in Europe is protecting consumer welfare, but the application of those laws benefits competitors and comes at a cost to European consumers, who no longer have access to the best products because there is no incentive for companies to produce them in the first place. Why compete to produce the best product if the ultimate outcome is to declare that competition unlawful?
The positive economic impact of the U.S. antitrust laws is not merely theoretical. The U.S. leads the world in research and development spending, with tech companies representing the nation’s top five spenders with investments totaling more than $75 billion in 2018. Overall, tech companies – fueled by innovation, investment, and entrepreneurship – have substantially contributed to economic growth in the U.S. These companies continually invest in research and development to innovate, introduce new products, and stay competitive. Tech companies rank second (behind the U.S. telecom sector) in U.S. capital expenditures. And there is no end in sight to these investments. Venture capital investing has also soured in the U.S., providing startups with the capital required to innovate, compete, and grow. Over half of the world’s startups valued at more than $1 billion call the U.S. home; no other country in the world can make such a claim.